by Giancarlo Elia Valori
In the midst of growing tension between the North and South Korea, Prof. Giancarlo Elia Valori considers the option of a Korean reunification and analyzes the geopolitical aspects of such a move. Opinion
South Korean soldiers at Imjingang Station near the border village of the Panmunjom in Paju, South Korea (Photo: AP) |
If
the two Koreas reunified, as planned in 2000 with the joint declaration
of June 15, we would have an unreasonable merging of two radically
different political principles.
South Korea has chosen to be a periphery of the American
Empire, which uses the US economy on the basis of its internal cycles
and mature technologies that it exports by taking advantage of the low
cost of manpower and some raw materials.
North Korea played the Cold War card, supported only
partially by China and Russia, which used North Korea as a block for the
West and paid for said North Korea's commitment with political
stability and some economic aid.
The Cold War, however, is really over and this holds true both for North and for South Korea.
We need to think of new worlds and new "super-concept rules," to quote Wittgenstein.
Traditionally, unification is conceived as a Confederation,
as supported by South Korea, or as a Federation with wide autonomy for
both areas, as always supported by North Korea.
The two inter-Korean meetings held in 2000 and 2007 – with
the first one that even made the South Korean President be awarded the
Nobel Peace Prize for his Sunshine Policy – recorded excellent economic
results (including the free trade area of Kaesong and the tourist area
of Mount Gumgang), but no effective political results.
Indeed, in November 2010, the North Korean Minister for Reunification officially dismissed the Sunshine Policy as a failure.
This always happens when politicians are only interested in conveying a "good image."
However, let us better analyze the reunification policies
which are currently being proposed, also by authoritative US think
tanks.
The excessive psychologism – the flaw Husserl saw in the
European philosophy of his time – still characterizes the North American
analysis of strategic phenomena in Asia and the Middle East.
Hence, both in North and in South Korea, the phenomenology
of elites is often quite simplified and devoid of the necessary nuances.
The "states of mind" or the subjective tendencies of the
real members of the two countries’ ruling classes are not so relevant as
they may appear at first sight.
"Les faits ont la tĂȘte dure" (Common sense is not
so common) – to quote Voltaire – and elites do not live on psychology,
but enjoy verifiable and significant privileges that someone has to pay
anyway.
Meanwhile, the constitution establishing the North Korean
Workers' Party repeats still today that conquering South Korea
militarily is the primary strategic (and economic) goal of the North
Korean regime. Not to mention the fact that North Korea’s ruling class
is selected with military and national criteria, while South Korea’s
ruling class is more technocratic and less prone to accept the line of
military confrontation.
The difference is not marginal. Pending an inter-Korean
conflict, South Korea’s elites would escape to the United States –
thinking of being at home – while the North Korean ones would fight
their war until final victory.
Furthermore, in this Asian context, our American friends
quote the example of "de-Baathification" in Iraq after Saddam Hussein’s
fall.
Never was an example more dangerous for the theses it intends to uphold.
The abolition of Baath, namely the Party-State, and the
selective and loyalist mechanism of the ruling class in Syria and Iraq
was, on the contrary, a real strategic folly which voided Iraq and
certainly made it viable –to use the typical terminology of US strategic
analysis – not to the bipartite “democracy” which is so fashionable in
the Anglo-Saxon world, but rather to the Iranian regime and later to the
Sunni sword-jihad of ISIS.
This means also viable to the division of the areas of
influence in a country like Iraq, having a Shiite majority and a Sunni
area which, through the jihad, has now become a mass of geopolitical
maneuver for the Gulf powers.
Every manipulation of the historical heritage of peoples
and Nations is bound to lead to their fragmentation into new areas of
influence, which have often not even been foreseen by the crazy "social
engineers" who believe – as happened to the first US Governor of Baghdad
– they can use the same laws in force in Boston to regulate road
traffic in the Iraqi capital city.
Turkey, too, has got its hands on Iraq – obviously with a view to settling the Kurdish issue.
Furthermore, it seems to flout any "line" worked out within NATO, of which Turkey is a member.
From the Balkans’ wars – waged to avoid the globalization
of Russian oil and gas towards Europe and the Mediterranean region – to
the massive use of the Afghan jihad to destabilize and disrupt the
post-Yugoslav political system, to the stable destabilization – if I may
use this oxymoron – of the Maghreb region with the silly "Arab Springs"
to be completed with the end of Syria and its ethnic and religious
splitting up, it seems that the current US global strategy is designed
to disrupting every geopolitical region.
Nevertheless, if all countries become "liquid" and viable, every political contagion will tend to spread and worsen.
Just think of Macedonia’s current situation and the
not-so-secret plan to achieve a Great Islamized Albania, capable of
standing up to the Slavic and, hence, pro-Russian Serbia.
Reverting to the US line in this Korean region, the idea is
that of a reunification creating a favorable interest for the North
Korean ruling classes.
How? The North Korean system based on songbun, namely the traditional caste system, is further divided into 51 subgroups.
Obviously, as everywhere, the main criterion is loyalty to
the regime – hence I do not see how the North Korean elite can accept a
soft reunification, in which North Korea will inevitably lose a share of
power to preserve hegemony – although with fewer elitist "privileges" –
in a possible peaceful reunification with South Korea.
According to the most reliable calculations, approximately
4.4 million North Koreans can be part of the local "ruling class," but –
as those who are acquainted with Pareto’s and Veblen’s theories know
all too well – all elite classes are intrinsically factionist and must
have strong symbolic and material incentives to back the regime that
supports them.
Psychology and the democratic myth are not enough.
Suffice to recall the phenomenon of Ostalgie, namely the nostalgia felt by many German citizens and voters for aspects of life in East Germany after the reunification – Nost-Algie
for permanent and regular jobs, for the lack of unemployment, for the
authoritarian but effective Welfare of the old Sociality Unity Party of
Germany (SED).
Money, however, never pays for the symbol – hence intangible incentives must always be greater than the tangible ones.
There is also talk about a selective amnesty for North Korea’s defectors.
Why?
How could South Korea support this new share of frustrated
ruling classes coming from Pyongyang and what would be the strategic aim
of this operation?
We may assume that the aim would be voiding the North
Korean regime from inside – but are we really sure that the South Korean
ruling class can safely double its size, possibly incorporating the
North Korean songbun classes that are already accustomed to unlawful transactions?
Furthermore, a reunification would bring no concrete benefit to the South Koreans.
Quite the opposite. It would be necessary to support a
population – about 50% of North Korean inhabitants – who is well below
the typical economic standards of South Korea's working class.
According to our estimates, for the five years following
the reunification, this would create a public debt at least 24% higher
than expected – which is already approximately 40% – in a situation of
weak growth, due to the crisis and saturation of the US market and the
contraction of the domestic market.
Being a client state never pays.
In other words, this kind of reunification would certainly lead to the default of the South Korean government.
Furthermore, South Korea is currently bearing the brunt of
political uncertainty, after the impeachment of President Park Geun Hye –
not to mention the already described decrease of domestic consumption,
resulting from an excessive cyclical link to the US economy and the
decline of exports to China.
With a 2.6% planned growth throughout 2017, South Korea
certainly has not the potential to absorb or make credible its debt
generated by the costs of a reunification, regardless of its being an
elitist or mass reunification.
Even demography does not help, as the South Korean population is expected to start falling structurally next year.
Certainly, we must consider the North Korean manpower.
However, the labor force has a cost of training, obviously adding to the
cost of the means of production which should guarantee jobs precisely
to the North Korean workers.
It is worth recalling that it took over twenty years to
achieve homogeneous social and economic conditions between West Germany
and the old German Democratic Republic (DDR) – a goal that has not been
reached yet despite the Euro manipulation and the huge German
investment.
Moreover, at the time of Vereinigung, Germany was the third world economy and certainly not the respectable, but much smaller South Korea’s economy.
And what about China? Obviously, it is not interested in the Korean reunification.
In fact, if this were to happen, it would be the repetition
– in the Third Millennium – of the unification of Northern and Southern
Italy and, in this case, the economic and political "line" would be
dictated by South Korean and not by North Korea.
As can be easily imagined, China does not like this.
China has every interest in freezing any geopolitical issue
in Asia, by operating with peripheral states – as in the Roman legend
of the Horatii and Curiatii – by dividing and later linking them with
bilateral agreements.
In Asia, China wants to avoid everything that may lead to
the creation of a new strategic bloc capable of dictating certain
conditions to its geoeconomic and military system.
Considering that South Korea is always a US client state,
China would regard a reunification as an undesirable increase of the
North American potential in the safety buffer zone of its Eastern and
Southern coasts.
In many ways, however, not even the United States would benefit from the Korean reunification.
While there is no longer such a reason to keep large troops
in South Korea, the correlation of US interests is inevitably expected
to change, thus leaving the Korean Peninsula uncovered while the United
States is supposed to redeploy its armed forces in the Pacific, around
the South China Sea and in the Japanese safety buffer zone.
Currently, neither China nor Japan appreciates this new scenario of the American military power in Asia.
If the United States maintained a large amount of troops in
the new reunified Korea, everybody would regard this as only having the
aim of opposing China.
Not even Japan would benefit from a German-style reunification between the two Koreas.
Both South Korea and, potentially, even North Korea, are
now global competitors of Japan – not to mention the strategic bloc
represented for the country by an imperial "co-prosperity area" that a
reunited Korea would undermine.
There is no Japanese geopolitics not targeted to the whole Southeast Asia – it is not possible otherwise.
And this holds true both for the Empire – the Dai Nihon about which Haushofer spoke in the 20th century – and for the Japan regionalized by the United States.
Japan was defeated in World War II, but it is still able to
think big and really understand geopolitical issues without demonizing
its past and worshiping its old enemy.
Hence, what can be done? It is simple.
Reopen the Six-Party Talks circle, as well as fund specific
projects in North Korea and help its people with humanitarian aid, but
above all, with a peaceful reindustrialization policy going towards
Russia, China, the EU and, possibly, also the United States.
The Asian Bank for European Infrastructure and the European
financial institutions should take immediate action. In a new type of
nuclear negotiations, we should also rethink the civilian potential of
North Korea’s nuclear system for it to sell energy to its neighbors.
Obviously, the resumption of the Six-Party Talks should be
based on a reconstruction of North Korean free trade areas and on an
effective relationship with Russia and China, which should become the
new guarantors of the Korean Peninsula’s nuclear and economic balance.
Source: http://www.israeldefense.co.il/en/node/29500
Follow Middle East and Terrorism on Twitter
Copyright - Original materials copyright (c) by the authors.
No comments:
Post a Comment